首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   160篇
  免费   1篇
  2021年   2篇
  2019年   1篇
  2018年   2篇
  2017年   2篇
  2016年   3篇
  2014年   3篇
  2013年   9篇
  2012年   1篇
  2011年   11篇
  2010年   1篇
  2009年   6篇
  2008年   4篇
  2007年   12篇
  2006年   3篇
  2005年   7篇
  2004年   3篇
  2003年   4篇
  2002年   5篇
  2001年   7篇
  2000年   4篇
  1999年   3篇
  1998年   3篇
  1996年   2篇
  1995年   1篇
  1994年   2篇
  1993年   2篇
  1992年   2篇
  1991年   4篇
  1990年   5篇
  1988年   1篇
  1987年   3篇
  1986年   2篇
  1985年   1篇
  1984年   1篇
  1983年   5篇
  1982年   2篇
  1981年   1篇
  1980年   1篇
  1979年   1篇
  1976年   1篇
  1975年   3篇
  1974年   1篇
  1973年   4篇
  1972年   3篇
  1971年   2篇
  1970年   3篇
  1969年   1篇
  1968年   4篇
  1967年   1篇
  1966年   5篇
排序方式: 共有161条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
21.
22.
Theories of visual search have generally assumed that rejected distractors are marked so as to avoid further processing of these items (memory-driven search). To test this assumption, Horowitz and Wolfe (1998) developed the randomized search paradigm, in which standard static search is compared to dynamic search where items are randomly replotted at new locations throughout a trial. Memory-driven search predicts that search slopes should double in the dynamic condition. After reviewing earlier findings that slopes were similar in the two conditions, we present two new experiments. Experiment 1 replicated and extended our previous findings using a larger range of set sizes, a slower rate of change, and adding a fixed location dynamic condition. Experiment 2 employed stimuli that required overt fixation. Neither experiment showed evidence for memory-driven search. We conclude that visual search is best understood as a series of successive judgements of the momentary probability of target presence.  相似文献   
23.
24.
25.
26.
27.
The continuum of solutions constituting the bargaining set for n-person games in characteristic function form (n ≥ 4) reflects various degrees of determinateness to form a coalition, different requirements of stability, or different levels of competition among the players. At one end of this continuum is the kernel solution. A new solution, called the competitive bargaining set, constitutes the other extreme. It incorporates the concept of a multiobjection, which is based on the idea that threats may be perceived and considered simultaneously even though their simultaneous implementation is impossible.For the simple homogeneous majority games [n ? 2, 1, 1, …, 1] the competitive bargaining set (1) yields unique outcomes for each coalition structure, (2) coincides with von Neumann and Morgenstern's main simple solution for certain coalition structures, and (3) converges to Shapley value as n → ∞ when the grand coalition forms.Mathematical and experimental implications of the new solution are discussed briefly.  相似文献   
28.
An innovative employment counseling model, Customized Employment Supports, was developed for methadone‐treatment patients, a population with historically low employment rates. The effectiveness of a key component of the model, “vocational fieldwork,” the delivery of services in the community rather than only within the clinic, was assessed through a quasi‐experimental study of the first 55 patients receiving the model in 2 clinics. Employment outcomes after 6 months were compared between patients who received vocational fieldwork (n = 18) and those who did not (n = 37). Logistic regression analysis demonstrated that patients receiving vocational fieldwork had significantly better outcomes for competitive work, informal work, and any paid work.  相似文献   
29.
Amir Horowitz 《Erkenntnis》2005,63(1):133-138
In “Contents just are in the head” (Erkenntnis 54, pp. 321–4.) I have presented two arguments against the thesis of semantic externalism. In “Contents just aren’t in the head” Anthony Brueckner has argued that my arguments are unsuccessful, since they rest upon some misconceptions regarding the nature of this thesis. (Erkenntnis 58, pp. 1–6.) In the present paper I will attempt to clarify and strengthen the case against semantic externalism, and show that Brueckner misses the point of my arguments.  相似文献   
30.
Observers are poor at reporting the identities of objects that they have successfully tracked (Pylyshyn, Visual Cognition, 11, 801-822, 2004; Scholl & Pylyshyn, Cognitive Psychology, 38, 259-290, 1999). Consequently, it has been claimed that objects are tracked in a manner that does not encode their identities (Pylyshyn, 2004). Here, we present evidence that disputes this claim. In a series of experiments, we show that attempting to track the identities of objects can decrease an observer's ability to track the objects' locations. This indicates that the mechanisms that track, respectively, the locations and identities of objects draw upon a common resource. Furthermore, we show that this common resource can be voluntarily distributed between the two mechanisms. This is clear evidence that the location- and identity-tracking mechanisms are not entirely dissociable.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号